Chapter 6: The Economic Impact of Immigration David Coates



Download 101.5 Kb.
Page3/4
Date08.02.2021
Size101.5 Kb.
#109775
1   2   3   4
Employment
The employment consequences of immigration for native-born workers seem similarly limited in scale and focused in impact, in spite of the fact that “since 2000, the foreign-born have accounted for 47.3% of the net increase in the total labor force,”36 and that unemployment rates among immigrants remain lower than those among native-born workers. Some commentators compare recent unemployment growth among the native-born (2.3 million from March 2000 to March 2004) to employment growth among immigrants over the same period (again, 2.3 million); and tentatively suggest that immigrants have soaked up positions that otherwise native-born workers would have taken.37 They particularly point the finger at illegal immigrants.38 But the suggestion has to be a tentative one. The evidence of a direct linkage between the two is quite simply not there; and unemployment among native-born Americans remains low and steady in spite of immigration – it fell from 5.2% to 4.7% through 2006. David Jaeger’s figures suggest that “if the undocumented were removed from the labor force, there would be a short fall of 2.5 million low-skill workers,” and that although overall “there are enough out-of-work natives to replace undocumented workers, there is,” as we have just seen, “a severe mismatch between the skills of undocumented workers and the natives who would potentially replace them.”39 So, at most, the claim has to be that the unemployment figure would be even lower but for the presence of so many foreign-born workers; and yet even that claim is not sustained by the available research data. Certainly the Pew Hispanic Center found no such one-to-one correlation. On the contrary, their results suggest that “rapid increases in the foreign-born population at the state level are not associated with negative effects on the employment of native-born workers” in any consistent pattern. In 2000 25% of native-born workers lived in states where rapid immigration growth coincided with job growth for the native-born, and 15% did not.40

This lack of any consistent pattern suggests again that the impact of immigration on economic variables turns on whether immigrant and native-born labor substitute or complement each other. The negative impact of immigration is therefore likely to be more potent at the bottom of the skills hierarchy where the competition for work is at its most intense. The question there is normally whether native-born Americans would do the work now done by illegal immigrants if – because of their absence – those jobs attracted higher wages. Given the nature of the beast, that is a difficult question to answer with any precision, though Borjas and his colleagues recently used their already-cited “skill group” analysis to suggest a 3.5% increase in black unemployment and a 1.6% increase in white unemployment from any 10% immigrant-induced increase in labor supply.41 That calculation remains controversial, but even economists normally critical of Borjas’ work have reported that in the late 1980s immigration depressed employment rates for “low-skilled natives and earlier immigrants in a typical major city by 1-2 percentage points, and by 3-5 times as much in high-immigrant cities like Los Angeles or Miami.”42 So some slight negative impact of immigration on the job prospects of unskilled native-born labor does seem likely.

What we know with greater certainty is that when low paying jobs done by immigrants are offered to native-born workers without significant increases in wages, there is plenty of anecdotal evidence of limited take-up; and that when illegal immigrants are driven from employment by tighter law enforcement, replacing those workers often proves extraordinarily difficult. We also know that, thus far at least, there are no occupational categories from which immigrants can be said to have driven all native-born labor. On the contrary, a recent detailed analysis of 473 separate occupations found that there are “virtually no occupations in which a majority of workers are immigrants, let alone illegal aliens.”43 And economic theory would suggest that the pressure of migration on unemployment can be expected to be greatest in economies in which strong trade unions and high minimum wage thresholds block off wage-cutting as an alternative employer response. The United States is, of course, precisely not such an economy.

Moreover, one positive consequence of the presence of a hidden army of migrant labor – a positive for the official statistics at least – is that economic downturns do not inflate the official rate of unemployment as rapidly as might be expected, since many of the workers laid off do not, and cannot, register for unemployment relief. Illegal immigration, therefore, brings hidden unemployment as well as hidden employment: hidden unemployment imperfectly captured by the fall in the volume of remittances sent home by migrant labor. In the first half of 2006, the $23 billion volume of annual remittances flowing into Mexico was still rising at a rate of 26% a year. Twelve months and one recession later, the growth rate of those remittances stood at just 0.6%.44 The drying up of that flow cannot have been accidental.


Welfare
The fiscal burden of illegal immigration is easier to see, if equally easy to exaggerate. There are many claims made about the excessive pressure placed by illegal immigrants on health services and the penal system, when thus far at least illegal Mexican immigrants – and indeed legal ones – use health services and end up in jail at a lower rate than do native-born Americans.45 Nor is access to welfare easy for immigrants, legal or otherwise. It was, after all, a key feature of the 1996 welfare reform legislation that access to welfare programs by non-citizens was made more difficult. Such access was initially denied to all legal permanent residents of the United States by legislation passed in 996. That denial was later amended to apply only to new immigrants, who are now obliged to wait five years for eligibility for food stamps and Social Security Insurance. Not surprisingly perhaps, given this new legal climate, participation by non-citizens in welfare programs then declined. Participation by non-citizens in the Food Stamp Program fell 64% between 1996 and 2001.46 Immigrant participation in TANF (Temporary Assistance for Needy Families) also fell. Only participation by immigrant households in Medicaid has risen since 1996, and then only modestly.47

The households of legal immigrants still remain, however, heavier users of welfare programs overall than do the households of the native-born. 33% of immigrant-headed households currently use at least one major welfare program, as against 19% of native-headed households. This simply reflects the disproportionate representation of first-generation immigrant families in the ranks of the American poor; but then first generation immigrants are invariably poorer on average than the indigenous population. That poverty invariably fades as later generations experience both integration and social mobility; so as immigrant children and grandchildren rise socially and economically the initial modest fiscal burden of immigration normally gives way to a modest fiscal surplus. All the major studies that examine the economic impact of immigration over time, with the exception of those carried out by the Heritage Foundation (for which, see Chapter 12 of this volume), “suggest a modest positive influence on average. The fiscal impact of skilled immigrants is more strongly positive.”48 The NRC estimated that skilled immigrants make a positive contribution through their own earnings, and then through that of their children. The unskilled take longer. They are still in net deficit at the end of generation two, but the net loss is by then small and declining.49

Undocumented workers have no right to receive public benefits of any kind. Their children, however, are a different matter. Children born here, even to parents who are themselves illegally here, acquire citizenship by nature of their birthplace. With their parents earning little, those children become eligible for Medicaid and SCHIP: and their rate of participation in those programs is rising – from 45-47% in 1995 to 53-54% in 2005.50 The burden of illegal immigration on US welfare services – and hence on native-born tax-payers – is thus particularly concentrated on the very young, and therefore on the school system. Of the 50 million students in the public school system, currently 8.5 million are Latino. Illegal immigrant households are disproportionately young households. Pew estimated that in 2005 there were 1.8 million children in the unauthorized population, plus an additional 3.1 million citizen-children living in unauthorized families.51 Those children put significant pressure on already over-stretched school systems in many states, particularly the eight that receive probably two-thirds of all undocumented immigrants. In 2000, 43.4% of all school-age children in California had an immigrant mother. The Florida figure was 28.1% and New York’s was 27.1%.52 It is at the state level that the fiscal burden of illegal immigration is at its greatest.

The only counter-weight to that burden is the volume of taxation paid by illegal immigrants. Many have false papers, and make contributions to the Social Security fund (from which they will never draw themselves). The Social Security Administration estimates that the majority of funds paid in under names or Social Security numbers that don’t match their records comes from undocumented workers. By October 2005 those funds totaled $520 billion.53 All undocumented workers pay sales tax and indirectly property tax (through their rents). As many as one half to three-quarters of them work on false papers, and so pay income tax and Medicare taxes. The commodities they help to produce also garner additional sales taxes, so that when all this hidden tax-paying is factored in, the fiscal burden they trigger – though real – is significantly diminished. Just how diminished remains in dispute, and largely turns on who is doing the counting. Jack Martin from the Federation for American Immigration Reform recently estimated the fiscal cost of illegal immigration in California at $9 billion a year, and in New York State at $4.5 billion. Local immigrant advocacy groups challenged the accuracy of both those claims. They were more comfortable with studies like that carried out in North Carolina in 2006, which found the state’s growing Hispanic population – half of which is thought to be undocumented – contributing more than $9 billion to the local economy through purchases, taxes and labor, while costing the state budget a net $102 per Hispanic resident in health care, education and jail expenditure. Likewise, Oregon, where a 2007 study estimated taxation from and by undocumented immigrant labor as totaling anywhere between $231 million to $323 million: this in a state in which undocumented workers are ineligible for SCHIP, food stamps or even temporary cash assistance.54

One final addition to the fiscal cost-benefit analysis has to be the cost to the taxpayer of locating, detaining and deporting all illegal immigrants. The head of Immigration and Customs Enforcement was asked for that cost at a Senate hearing in September 2007. Her answer: “our agency has estimated that it would cost at least $94 billion.”55 The Center for American Progress has the figure higher: $230 billion over 5 years.56 Either way, it is a huge sum.



Download 101.5 Kb.

Share with your friends:
1   2   3   4




The database is protected by copyright ©essaydocs.org 2023
send message

    Main page